|
|
Carrots over Sticks
The case for environmental self-audits
by Alexander Volokh
Washington Monthly, June 1997
When people think of environmental battles, spotted owls, old-growth forests,
and Pacific salmon typically come to mind. Beer probably doesn�t. But that�s
what touched off one of today�s most heated environmental debates: What sort of
protection should companies be granted in exchange for conducting voluntary
environmental audits?
Air pollution agencies used to think beer brewers were clean people. An
Environmental Protection Agency document published in September 1985 found that
volatile organic compound (VOC) emissions from beer fermentation were
negligible. Likewise, a 1983 report by the California Air Resources Board
concluded that the state's breweries produced 20.7 million barrels of beer each
year and in the process released only 42.3 tons of VOCs.
But all that changed in 1992 when the Colorado-based Coors Brewing Company
became the first major brewery in the United States to do a comprehensive,
voluntary investigation of its VOC emissions. (Brewery scientists had long
suspected that EPA figures underestimated company emissions.) The investigation
found that when beer is spilled during the making, packaging, and disposal
process, large quantities of VOCs are released into the air. As the producer of
about 20 million barrels of beer per year, Coors alone was releasing 650 to 750
tons of VOCs -- about 17 times more than originally thought.
Environmentalists, regulators, and industry alike love the idea of audits. But
after sharing the results of its review with public authorities, Coors
discovered a significant downside to self-auditing. In July 1993, the Colorado
Department of Health -- allegedly under pressure from the federal EPA -- issued
Coors a compliance order containing a $1.05 million civil penalty for violations
of state air pollution laws. The fine was also to include a to-be-determined-
later "economic benefit payment" to the state for money the company had saved by
not complying with the laws. The 23-page order listed 189 violations -- 100 air
pollution emission notification violations, 56 permit violations, and 33 VOC
violations. All but the 33 VOC violations were essentially claims that Coors
had not submitted the proper paperwork to the Health Department -- for VOC
sources that no one even knew about until the audit.
This was the largest fine ever imposed by the state for an air pollution
violation. Coors argued that it was being unfairly punished for voluntarily
revealing problems that both regulators and major brewers had missed, and warned
that such fines would go a long way to discourage other companies from
conducting self-audits. (Coors had already spent 18 months and $1.5 million
conducting the study.)
In February 1994, the fine was reduced. Coors agreed to pay a $100,000 fine and
a $137,000 economic benefit payment, relinquish 70 tons of pollution allowances
it held for the release of VOCs, and reduce its annual VOC, sulfur dioxide, and
nitrogen oxide emissions. The agreement also included a schedule to bring all
of Coors's emission sources into compliance with state regulations within two
years.
Carrots vs. Sticks
The Coors episode was the catalyst for Colorado's adopting an "audit privilege"
law, based on the premise that it's wrong to punish someone for voluntarily
discovered, voluntarily revealed information that they otherwise wouldn't have
known about or disclosed at all.
Most "audit-privilege" laws have two components: privilege and immunity. The
"privilege" component guarantees that the audit is privileged information. In
other words, information discovered in an audit, the audit documents themselves,
and any related testimony are inadmissible as evidence against a company in an
administrative, civil, or criminal proceeding. The law does not, however, cover
information that the firm is already required to reveal by other regulations or
information about violations discovered independently, for instance, by a
neighbor. In addition, the law requires that the company, having discovered
evidence of a violation, promptly tell the regulating agency, in this case the
state health department, and then fix the problem.
The "immunity" component protects companies that voluntarily find, reveal, and
fix violations from penalties. The environmental agency can still require the
company to take certain steps related to damage control, but punitive sanctions
are forbidden. Again, the immunity is limited; it doesn't apply to intentional
or reckless violations or to violations that caused on-site injury or
substantial harm to people, property, or the environment.
Today, about 19 states have such laws. A handful of others are considering
them, and bills to do the same on the federal level have been introduced in
Congress. According to Russell Harding, commissioner of the Michigan Department
of Environmental Protection, privilege is becoming increasingly necessary thanks
to the popularity of ISO 14001, the International Standards Organization�s
evaluation program that certifies companies as having sound environmental
practices. ISO 14001 mandates self-auditing as a condition for certification.
But many companies who want to pursue certification don't want to risk their own
audits being used against them. "It is an issue of fear," says Harding.
Regulated entities and the employees who provide the information for the audit
feel that they can't be entirely candid for fear of what regulators or third
parties -- through citizen suits -- will do to them. This is particularly
troublesome for small businesses that can't afford to spend a lot of money on
legal advice. When the costs of knowing the law are too high, companies will
just risk violating it.
Corporate surveys suggest that privilege laws would significantly increase both
the willingness of organizations to conduct self-audits and the effectiveness of
the audits themselves. Around 75 percent of companies already do environmental
audits, according to a 1995 Price Waterhouse survey. Of those, 81 percent try
to protect the information acquired using existing legal mechanisms like the
attorney-client privilege. But using the attorney-client privilege limits the
audit's usefulness, since privilege is lost if you share the information with
someone like the plant manager, company scientists, or environmental
consultants. The survey also showed that nearly two-thirds of companies that
conduct environmental audits would expand their programs if penalties were
eliminated for problems that the organizations themselves identified, reported,
and corrected. More than 45 percent of such companies explained that they're
unwilling to expand their auditing program because the information could be used
against them in a litigation or civil enforcement action. Among the companies
that don't perform audits, 20 percent said that they fear the information could
be used against them. And a separate survey of firms in Indiana, where audits
are privileged, found that 66 percent of small businesses wouldn't do audits if
government prosecutors could access the reports.
Many environmentalists oppose audit-privilege laws, branding them "secrecy
laws." Nor is the federal EPA wild about the idea. As one EPA official
recently told State Environmental Monitor, enforcement actions often
depend on "tips and confidential sources," and if this information becomes
privileged -- so that employees' testimony about an audit is unusable --
enforcers' jobs become tougher.
Many attorneys general agree. In a June 1996 letter to Rep. Gary Condit (D-
Cal.), who supports audit privilege laws, the National District Attorneys
Association wrote that corporate records are often needed to make a
determination that "knowledge and intent" were involved in a violation and that
criminal charges are warranted. They argued that to successfully overcome a
privilege and prosecute a company criminally, the state would have to "undergo
great hardship," and that the conviction may well be overturned "if any taint
can be shown or even intimated."
Federal regulators are equally concerned about the immunity aspect of such
arrangements. Economic benefit payments have become a staple of federal
environmental enforcement, and the government believes such payments are
necessary to prevent companies from profiting from violations. Immunity, which
would prevent regulators from imposing any penalties, could make it difficult
for the government to guarantee a "level playing field" for companies who have
maintained sound environmental practices.
But state agencies, such as the Texas Natural Resources Conservation Commission,
would dispute the claim that audits hinder enforcement. The TNRCC considers the
Texas Audit Privilege Act of 1995 an additional enforcement resource.
The commission reasons that it will never have enough resources to monitor
everybody, and since environmental regulation already relies heavily on
self-policing and self-reporting, we might as well encourage the regulated to do
their job right.
So why, if they have immunity, would a company need privilege? For one thing, a
good audit document is a frank discussion of the environmental effects of all
company processes -- some of which may be proprietary -- revealing in detail the
thoughts and judgments of company scientists. And while the public has an
interest in knowing actual violations uncovered by an audit, it is not entitled
to know about the specifics of a company's proprietary processes or scientific
analyses.
Also, audit laws sheild a company from government-imposed penalties, but do
nothing to prevent citizen plaintiffs from filing suit. If information
uncovered during an audit could be used against the company in a lawsuit by any
group other than the government, companies would have little incentive to ever
open themselves up to voluntary review.
As for the EPA's point about fines being necessary to maintain a "level playing
field," consider again the case of Coors, which did the $1.5 million audit, told
the agency, then shelled out another $237,000 in fines. Even though other
brewers benefited from the information Coors uncovered, they neither had to
shell out the money for an audit nor face the resultant penalties. To Coors,
talk of a level playing field must sound rich.
Battle of the Regulators
But suppose the EPA is right about audit laws making enforcement more difficult.
This still begs the question of what should take precedence in environmental
law: prosecuting a company or improving the environment? If the threat of
prosecution prevents a company from taking action that would improve the
environment, then making the enforcers' jobs tougher in those cases may be a
good idea. After all, the ultimate goal of environmental regulation and
enforcement shouldn't be to rack up fines and lawsuits, but to encourage
companies to minimize their negative impact on the environment. As Howard
Wetters, a Democratic state representative from Michigan, put it, "We want to
make sure the environment is cleaned up. We're more interested in that than in
simply punishing people. I think that philosophy, as I've seen it in
agriculture, has been a far more successful way of enforcing and regulating than
through the adversarial process we have used to enforce environmental laws."
Instead, the EPA has suggested (over the objections of Congress) that it may
increase enforcement -- including "overfiling," or filing its own lawsuit if it
dislikes what the state is doing -- in states with highly protective audit laws
like Michigan, Colorado, and Texas. Moreover, the EPA is threatening to "take
back" a whole range of activities currently delegated to the states, like solid
waste management, wastewater permiting, or asbestos programs. The EPA has
specifically targeted Idaho's air pollution operating permit program, which the
state runs by delegation from the federal government under the 1990 Clean Air
Act amendments.
This is where, for state environmental officials, it gets personal. James Seif,
Pennsylvania's Environmental Protection Secretary, accused the EPA of being on a
vendetta against states that don't toe the line; "it appears to be our turn in
this pattern of public attacks," he lamented to The New York Times. Last
November, Michigan's commissioner Harding and 14 other state environmental
commissioners sent an angry letter to EPA administrator Carol Browner, asking
that the agency not "unduly interfere" with state enforcement matters without
solid evidence that audit laws "undermine state enforcement authority." These
complaints are echoed by observers from both ends of the political spectrum. On
the right, the Washington Legal Foundation, a public-interest law firm, has
characterized the EPA's behavior as "bludgeoning" and "blackmail"; according to
a WLF report, states with audit-privilege laws haven't reported a decrease in
environmental enforcement activity or in environmental quality due to such laws,
though they are now getting more environmental results for less money. On the
left, the Progressive Policy Foundation has suggested that auditing makes
"eminent sense" and that state laws should be treated as a "demonstration
project" to find out which enforcement strategies work and which ones don't.
Currently, the EPA has its own audit-privilege policy, and notes that since its
implementation in January 1996, 76 companies have disclosed violations -- with
most paying no penalties. But the EPA's policy is substantially weaker than
that of many state programs and ultimately can be expected to yield smaller
benefits than other bills under proposal. The EPA puts more requirements on
companies that want to benefit from audit privilege, and often only reduces
fines instead of eliminating them. Moreover, the EPA's policy is not binding on
the EPA and has no effect on the Department of Justice, which can prosecute
criminal cases regardless of what the EPA recommends. It also applies only to
government prosecution, providing no protection against suits by outside
organizations; and it only covers corporate environmental violations, not
violations by individual employees. Finally, it only protects the audit
documents themselves, not testimony about them, so a prosecutor who wants to use
audit information against the company can still make a member of the audit team
testify about what was in the audit.
State audit-privilege laws don't constitute a rollback of environmental
protection; they are not intended to pre-empt existing federal laws. All
regulations on the books will remain on the books, which means that federal
enforcers will continue to keep an eye on what smokestacks in Ohio are doing to
the rivers or trees in Indiana. Therefore, any environmental "race to the
bottom" would be unlikely.
Audit-privilege laws, in the end, are good policy. Whether you believe
organizations conduct self-audits in the name of good corporate citizenship or
because they want to keep regulators off their backs doesn't really matter. The
result is the same: Companies pay greater attention to their environmental
practices. These laws improve environmental quality by giving firms incentive
to discover and correct problems. They save taxpayers money by allowing
enforcement agencies to concentrate on prosecuting "bad actors" -- knowing
violators who act recklessly and cause harm. They help move enforcement
agencies away from a "bean-counting" mindset that leads them to obsess about the
number of enforcement actions and monetary penalties issued because they have no
other definition of "success." They promote fairness by not punishing people
who voluntarily reveal information they didn't have to find out about in the
first place. And most importantly, the laws foster an atmosphere of cooperation
between the regulators and the regulated -- an atmosphere which is sorely
needed.
Alexander Volokh is a policy analyst at the Reason Foundation, a public
policy think tank in Los Angeles.
Return to environment page
Return to home page
|